Advertisement
Advertisement
This photo taken early on April 12, 2015 shows a badly damaged Lamborghini car and debris in a tunnel after a crash involving a Ferrari in Beijing. The accident sparked an online controversy about the identities of the drivers. Photo: AFP
Opinion
The View
by Richard Wong
The View
by Richard Wong

These Nobel laureates tinkered with ‘health’ and other ideas to help win the war on poverty

New thinking on a complex social problem has helped to usher in vast improvements in well-being for humanity

Professor Angus Deaton won the Nobel Prize in Economics this year for his work on consumption, poverty and welfare. I have always greatly admired his work and I use his book, The Great Escape, in my freshman course that takes a close look at poverty.

Deaton’s work has three critical elements for understanding poverty and welfare in both developing and developed countries.

First is that income is not the only thing that matters in determining the well-being of individuals and households. By implication, the obsession in both rich and poor societies with using income to measure welfare is incomplete and could be misleading for our understanding and policy design to tackle poverty.

Time free from work is a non-income measure of well-being. Increases in productivity lead to higher incomes but also reduce the amount of time a person spends at work. Time not spent in work is not idle or wasted. It is often spent investing in human capital (including studying, training, exercising and sleeping) and in play.

Increases in life expectancy due to better health have also greatly increased well-being. A better measure of well-being therefore must also include the additional time available to an individual when productivity, health and income increase.

To appreciate the significance of this, consider the consequences of recognising health as an element of well-being. A general empirical observation is that the rich have better health than the poor, and people in developed nations on average have better health than those in developing countries, as reflected in longer lives, fewer sick days, taller body heights, and other measures of health robustness.

These indicators are strongly correlated with income across individuals, across countries, and over time. But the correlation is not perfect. It cannot be reduced only to income effects.

In fact, the health gap between rich and poor individuals, and between rich and poor nations, has both narrowed and widened depending on which age groups are affected by advances in medical treatment.

Empirical economic work by Gary Becker (also a Nobel economist) and others have found medical and scientific breakthroughs that reduce mortality among individuals below 50 from infectious, respiratory, digestive, congenital, perinatal, and “ill-defined” conditions are responsible for most of the increase in life expectancy. This not only increases welfare for all – it reduces relative inequality both within and across countries, and contributes to a more equal distribution of well-being.

However, recent medical breakthroughs that reduce mortality after age 50 from such things as AIDS and conditions affecting the nervous system, senses organs, and heart and circulatory system, have contributed to increased health inequality across countries and also within rich nations.

The second critical element of Deaton’s work is his deep understanding of individual consumption choices. He focused on the lifetime outcomes of well-being and income and not just at a particular moment in time, which the popular Gini-coefficient of household income dispersion measures.

Milton Friedman was the first to emphasise that individual and household incomes vary considerably from year to year, and Deaton developed that idea further. Evidence came in a study by sociologists Mark Rank, Thomas Hirschl, and Kirk Foster that looked at 44 years of longitudinal data for individuals in the US aged 25 to 60 and found 12 per cent of the population spent at least one year in the top 1 per cent of the income distribution over their working lifetimes and a whopping 73 per cent spent a year in the top 20 per cent.

A big part of short-term mobility in income is simply transitory ups and downs. A relevant consideration of well-being is therefore total outcome over a lifetime. One might more usefully ask whether income redistribution policies that raise the incomes of the measured poor can reduce lifetime and cross-generational income differences between rich and poor.

The third critical element of Deaton’s work is that it reminds us how economic theory can guide policy design to alleviate poverty and inequality. Deaton said that health is as important as income in human well-being, and that lifetime outcomes are more relevant than short term gains. His work on consumption guides us to focus on the importance of education, health care, and early childhood intervention policies that help young children in poor families, as a critical focus of any policy to alleviate poverty and inequality.

Income redistribution policies that are aimed to support the consumption of the poor will be successful in reducing poverty measures based on Gini-coefficients, but Deaton has taught us that the alleviation of poverty is not about fixing measures. He also recognises the inequalities that reward effort, risk taking, and luck are necessary even as society seeks to escape from poverty.

Richard Wong Yue-chim is Philip Wong Kennedy Wong Professor in Political Economy at the University of Hong Kong

Post