Advertisement
Advertisement
The European Central Bank headquarters in Frankfurt, Germany. By joining the euro, Italy surrendered monetary sovereignty to an external, independent decision-maker, the ECB. Photo: Bloomberg
Opinion
The View
by Dani Rodrik
The View
by Dani Rodrik

If the euro is to remain viable, the democratic legitimacy of ECB decisions cannot be taken for granted

Dani Rodrik says the Italian president’s veto of a minister’s appointment in the name of ensuring market stability, which was criticised for undermining his country’s democracy, raises issues that must be addressed when policymakers delegate decision-making to unelected bodies

When Italy’s president recently vetoed the appointment of the Eurosceptic Paolo Savona as finance minister in the government proposed by the Five Star Movement-League party alliance, did he safeguard or undermine his country’s democracy? The question goes to the heart of democratic legitimacy.

The euro represents a treaty commitment from which there is no clear exit within prevailing rules of the game. President Sergio Mattarella and his defenders point out that an exit from the euro had not been subject to debate in the election campaign that brought the populist coalition to power, and that Savona’s appointment threatened a financial market meltdown and economic chaos.

Mattarella’s detractors argue that he overstepped his authority and has allowed financial markets to veto the selection of a minister by a popularly elected government.

By joining the euro, Italy surrendered monetary sovereignty to an external, independent decision-maker, the European Central Bank. It also undertook specific commitments with respect to the conduct of its fiscal policy, though these constraints are not as “hard” as those framing monetary policy.

These obligations place real limits on the Italian authorities’ macroeconomic policy choices. In particular, the absence of a domestic currency means Italians cannot choose their own inflation target or devalue their currency vis-à-vis foreign currencies. They also have to keep their fiscal deficits below certain ceilings.

Supporters of the anti-establishment Five Star Movement party join a rally in Naples, Italy, on May 29, calling for President Sergio Mattarella to be impeached after he blocked the appointment of a Eurosceptic finance minister. Photo: EPA-EFE

Such external restraints need not conflict with democracy. Sometimes it makes sense for the electorate to tie its hands when doing so helps it achieve better outcomes. Hence the principle of “democratic delegation”: democracies can enhance their performance by delegating aspects of decision-making to independent agencies.

Policymakers have to pay closer attention to the demanding requirements of delegating decisions to unelected bodies

The canonical case for democratic delegation arises when there is a paramount need for credible commitment to a particular course of action. Monetary policy is perhaps the clearest instance of this. Many economists subscribe to the view that central banks can generate output and employment gains through expansionary monetary policy only if they are able to produce surprise inflation in the short term.

But, because expectations adjust to central bank behaviour, discretionary monetary policy is futile: it yields higher inflation but no output or employment increases. Accordingly, it is far better to insulate monetary policy from political pressures by delegating it to technocratic, independent central banks that are charged with the singular objective of price stability.

Superficially, the euro and the ECB can be seen as the solution to this inflationary conundrum in Europe. They protect the Italian electorate from their politicians’ counterproductive inflationary tendencies. But there are peculiarities to the European situation that make the democratic delegation argument more suspect.

The European Central Bank bears responsibility for monetary policy for the euro zone as a whole. As a result, it will be generally less responsive to an individual country’s economic circumstances. Photo: SCMP Pictures

For one thing, the ECB bears responsibility for monetary policy for the euro zone as a whole rather than Italy alone. As a result, it will be generally less responsive to Italian economic circumstances than a purely Italian, but equally independent, central bank would have been.

As Paul Tucker, a former deputy governor of the Bank of England, discusses in his masterful recent book Unelected Power: The Quest for Legitimacy in Central Banking and the Administrative State, the argument for democratic delegation is a subtle one. The distinction between policy goals and how they are implemented needs to be clear. Insofar as they entail distributional consequences or trade-offs between contending goals (employment versus price stability, for example), policy objectives have to be determined through politics.

Delegation is warranted at best in the conduct of policy that serves politically determined objectives. Tucker argues, correctly, that few independent agencies are based on a careful application of principles that would pass the test of democratic legitimacy.

This shortcoming is far worse in the case of delegation to international agencies or treaties. Too often, international economic commitments serve not to fix democratic failures at home, but to privilege corporate or financial interests and undermine domestic social bargains.

When Italian President Sergio Mattarella cited the reaction of financial markets in justifying his veto of an anti-euro finance minister, he reinforced suspicions that the EU’s institutional arrangements are in place to privilege corporate or financial interests, to the detriment of domestic social bargains. Photo: Bloomberg
The European Union’s legitimacy deficit derives from the popular suspicion that its institutional arrangements have veered too far from the former to the latter. When Mattarella cited the reaction of financial markets in justifying his veto of Savona, he reinforced those suspicions.

If the euro – and indeed the EU itself – is to remain viable and democratic at the same time, policymakers will have to pay closer attention to the demanding requirements of delegating decisions to unelected bodies. This does not mean they should resist surrendering sovereignty to supranational agencies. But they should recognise that economists’ and other technocrats’ policy preferences rarely endow policies with sufficient democratic legitimacy on their own.

They should promote such a delegation of sovereignty only when it truly enhances the long-term performance of their democracies, not when it merely advances the interests of globalist elites.

Dani Rodrik, professor of international political economy at Harvard University’s John F. Kennedy School of Government, is the author of Straight Talk on Trade: Ideas for a Sane World Economy. Copyright: Project Syndicate

This article appeared in the South China Morning Post print edition as: Question of democracy
Post