Advertisement
Advertisement
A shop for Chinese telecom giant Huawei displays a 5G logo in Beijing on May 25, 2020. Photo: AFP
Opinion
Opinion
by Dani Rodrik
Opinion
by Dani Rodrik

Huawei’s troubles show the limits of the old trade order in a world of data, software and AI

  • The Huawei case is a harbinger of a world in which national security, privacy and economics will interact in complicated ways
  • Countries must agree on a new regulatory patchwork which allows them to pursue their own interests without exporting their problems
The international trade regime we now have, expressed in the rules of the World Trade Organisation and other agreements, is not of this world. It was designed for a world of cars, steel and textiles, not one of data, software and artificial intelligence. Already under severe pressure from China’s rise and the backlash against hyper-globalisation, it is utterly inadequate to face the three main challenges these new technologies pose.
First, there is geopolitics and national security. Digital technologies allow foreign powers to hack industrial networks, conduct cyberespionage and manipulate social media. Russia has been accused of interfering in elections in the United States and other Western countries through fake news sites and the manipulation of social media. The US government has cracked down on the Chinese giant Huawei because of fears that the company’s links to the Chinese government make its telecoms equipment a security threat.
Second, there are concerns about individual privacy. Internet platforms are able to collect huge amounts of data on what people do online and offline, and some countries have stricter rules than others to regulate what they can do with it. The European Union, for example, has enacted fines for companies that fail to protect EU residents’ data.

Third, there is economics. New technologies give a competitive edge to large companies that can accumulate enormous global market power. Economies of scale and scope and network effects produce winner-take-all outcomes, and mercantilist policies and other government practices can result in some firms having what looks like an unfair advantage.

For example, state surveillance has allowed Chinese firms to accumulate huge amounts of data, which in turn has enabled them to corner the global facial recognition market.

00:59

China’s facial recognition technology identifies people wearing masks amid the Covid-19 epidemic

China’s facial recognition technology identifies people wearing masks amid the Covid-19 epidemic

A common response to these challenges is to call for greater international coordination and global rules. Transnational regulatory cooperation and antitrust policies could produce new standards and enforcement mechanisms.

Even where a truly global approach is not possible – because authoritarian and democratic countries have deep disagreements about privacy, for example – it is still possible for democracies to cooperate among themselves and develop joint rules.

The benefits of common rules are clear. In their absence, practices such as data localisation, local cloud requirements, and discrimination in favour of national champions create economic inefficiencies insofar as they segment national markets.

They reduce the gains from trade and prevent companies from reaping the benefits of scale. And governments face the constant threat that their regulations will be undermined by companies operating from jurisdictions with laxer rules.

But in a world where countries have different preferences, global rules – even when they are feasible – are inefficient in a broader sense. Any global order must balance the gains from trade (maximised when regulations are harmonised) against the gains from regulatory diversity (maximised when each national government is entirely free to do what it wants).

University students visit the Huainan Big Data Exhibition Centre in Huainan, east China’s Anhui province, on July 9, 2019. Photo: Xinhua

If hyper-globalisation has already proved brittle, it is in part because policymakers prioritised the gains from trade over the benefits of regulatory diversity. This mistake should not be repeated with new technologies.

In fact, the principles that should guide our thinking on new technologies are no different from those for traditional domains. Countries may devise their own regulatory standards and define their own national security requirements.

They may do what is required to defend these standards and their national security, including through trade and investment restrictions. But they have no right to internationalise their standards and try to impose their regulations on other countries.

Consider how these principles would apply to Huawei. The US government has prevented Huawei from acquiring American companies, restricted its operations in the US, launched legal proceedings against its senior management, pressured foreign governments not to work with it and, most recently, banned US companies from selling chips to Huawei’s supply chain anywhere in the world.
There is little evidence that Huawei has engaged in spying on behalf of the Chinese government. But that does not mean it will not do so in the future. Western technical experts who have examined Huawei’s code have been unable to rule out the possibility. The opacity of corporate practices in China could well obscure Huawei’s links to the Chinese government.

Under these circumstances, there is a plausible national security argument for the US – or any other country – to restrict Huawei’s operations within its own borders. Other countries, including China, are not in a position to second-guess this decision.

The export ban on US companies, however, is harder to justify on national security grounds than the ban on Huawei’s US-based operations. If Huawei’s operations in third countries pose a security risk to those countries, their governments are in the best position to assess the risks and decide whether a shutdown is appropriate.

Moreover, the US ban confronts other countries with severe economic repercussions. It creates significant adverse effects for national telecoms companies like BT, Deutsche Telekom, Swisscom, and others in no fewer than 170 countries that rely on Huawei’s kits and hardware. Perhaps worst hit are poor countries in Africa that are overwhelmingly dependent on the company’s cheaper equipment.
An engineer from EE, a wireless network provider owned by BT Group, checks 5G masts and Huawei 5G equipment during trials in the City of London on March 15, 2019. Europe would fall behind the US and China in the race to install the next generation of wireless networks if governments banned Huawei over security fears, according to an internal assessment by Deutsche Telekom. Photo: Bloomberg

In short, the US is free to close its market to Huawei. But US efforts to internationalise its domestic crackdown lack legitimacy.

The Huawei case is a harbinger of a world in which national security, privacy and economics will interact in complicated ways. Global governance and multilateralism will often fail, for both good and bad reasons.

The best we can expect is a regulatory patchwork, based on clear ground rules that help empower countries to pursue their core national interests without exporting their problems to others. Either we design this patchwork ourselves, or we will end up, willy-nilly, with a messy, less efficient and more dangerous version.

Dani Rodrik, Professor of International Political Economy at Harvard University’s John F. Kennedy School of Government, is the author of Straight Talk on Trade: Ideas for a Sane World Economy. Copyright: Project Syndicate

21